“The top-down approach by many [Peak Oil] analysts tends to ignore the explanatory variables behind oil supply trends. [They] merely extrapolate recent trends, especially if they are declining. Oil prices, fiscal regimes, and other factors that influence investment and supply trends are ignored….”
“While it is true that the success of any given wildcat cannot be predicted, you can forecast that discoveries will continue to occur and that a certain percentage of exploratory wells will find oil. And where the resource base has a history of exploration, the confidence about discoveries grows, especially in terms of the success rate.”
Abstract: The presumption that the inability to predict a given oil field discovery translates into an assumption of no discoveries is a primary factor behind neo-Malthusian pessimism about oil supply. Given data for a basin, it can be safely assumed that a certain level of discoveries will continue.
————–
Peak Oil proponents, and neo-Malthusians in general, tend to suffer from a serious methodological problem, one that has afflicted their analyses of resources for many years.
With some justification, they point to the fact that petroleum (and other mineral resources) are extracted, not manufactured–as in “you have to find the oil before you can produce it.” This is a major part of the long-standing disagreement from some geologists who argue that economists believe higher prices ‘automatically’ translate into discoveries.
In fact, economists believe that higher prices will, other things equal, result in higher investment, which will yield discoveries and production. Geologists will tell you this concept is flawed because no given discovery can be predicted, and therefore none should be assumed. (Technology, however, is increasingly changing even this long-standing view as IT substitutes for ‘dumb iron’ in the ground.)
There is some basic logic here: any number of automobile plants can be constructed anywhere, so you don’t need to predict the precise locations but can assume they will be built. Oil production can only occur in places where there is oil underground, and you can’t be sure that it will be there in advance.
Thus predicting 20 years of discoveries thus seems impossible, and I have had numerous challenges to my supply forecasts that consist of little more than “You can’t tell us where it will be found, therefore you shouldn’t assume it will be.”
Bad Thinking, Bad Policy
This attitude has been known to influence policy, usually detrimentally. The U.S. suffered natural gas shortages in the 1970s because price controls suppressed upstream investment and encouraged consumption. Similarly, British Gas, as the only legal buyer of supply from the U.K. North Sea, kept prices for domestic producers at a fraction of what it paid Norway for imported gas, arguing that higher prices for domestic producers couldn’t be guaranteed to provide new discoveries. In both cases, decontrol brought forth major new supplies.
While it is true that the success of any given wildcat cannot be predicted, you can forecast that discoveries will continue to occur and that a certain percentage of exploratory wells will find oil. And where the resource base has a history of exploration, the confidence about discoveries grows, especially in terms of the success rate.
Actual find sizes fluctuate substantially (Figure 1), but a trend is usually discernible in a given basin. Even more, where there are existing reserves, more intense exploitation of them can generate reserve additions, which in a typical year account for the majority of ‘new’ resources.
Figure 1. UK Field Sizes by Year of Discovery
Source: UK Brown Books, data publication ceased in late 1990s.
As I have noted for roughly three decades, nearly all forecasts for non-Middle East production have been too pessimistic since the early 1980s. Typical is to project a short-term increase, reaching a peak then declining. (Figure 2 is one example.) This appears to be a type of horizon effect, a bias set in by the concern about predicting future discoveries. You don’t know where oil will be found, so you are reluctant to predict that it will be. This is a problem that particularly plagues neo-Malthusians, but also conventional forecasters.
Figure 2. The Evolution of DOE’s Non-OPEC Third World Oil Production Forecasts
Some argue that the uncertain probability of discoveries requires a conservative posture, but the reality is that assuming no discoveries in an area with a track record of finds is actually radical. To observe a historical discovery rate, as in Fig. 3 for the United States and Figure 4 for Norway, and to assume that at any given point the discovery rate will drop to zero, is roughly the same as omitting discoveries altogether, which is nonsense.
The best analogy is to neo-Malthusians who argue that future technological progress cannot be predicted, and so should not be assumed. Typical is this quote from 1977’s Ecoscience: “It is certainly evident that no conceivable increase in the food supply can keep up with current population growth rates indefinitely.”[1]
Figure 3. Success Rate for U.S. Exploratory Wells
Figure 4. Success Rate for Norwegian Exploratory Wells
Company Logic
At the company level, Bijan Mossavar-Rahmani, an international oil and gas executive, once explained to me that most companies try to minimize risk and financial outlays by signing exploration contracts for new areas that commit them to as little work as possible, with the intention to continue drilling only if a discovery is made.
Otherwise, they drop the sometimes very substantial and effectively untested acreage and go elsewhere. But his strategy was to recognize that an oil province will likely yield discoveries given enough time and effort. So the strategy was to continue to explore beyond the initial commitment until, hopefully, the code was cracked.
Institutions Matter
A flaw in the simplistic neoclassical economics approach was revealed in the mid-1970s, after the first oil-price spike, when several major studies relied on the “price elasticity of supply” to forecast oil production. (This approach projected the change in supply relative to the change in price.)
Since the market had never experienced such a price increase before, there was no data to provide for an estimate, so the elasticity was assumed at 0.3, which meant a 300% increase in price would generate a 90% increase in production.
Clearly, this approach failed, primarily because
a) producers raised taxes, reducing the impact of higher prices on investment
b) factor costs soared with rising investment, especially in the United States.
Thus, higher investment did not yield proportionately higher operations. And more resource nationalism combined with greater perceived political risk directed a lot of the investment to high-cost U.S. basins. (Peak oil theorists have perceived no supply response relative to the huge increase of drilling in the U.S. during this period, but the reality was a shift from a 300 tb/d/yr decline rate to flat production. Not earthshaking but hardly trivial.)
Getting Realistic
The top-down approach by many analysts tends to ignore the explanatory variables behind oil supply trends.
Peak-oil advocates like Colin Campbell, Jean Laherrere, Michael Smith and others merely extrapolate recent trends, especially if they are declining. Oil prices, fiscal regimes, and other factors that influence investment and supply trends are ignored, the assumption being that geology is the determining element and as such cannot be reversed, although trends change.
Obviously, analyzing these factors at the national level for dozens of oil producing countries is a task beyond nearly everyone, and predicting them in the long-term future for individual nations is virtually impossible.
Supply forecasts that focus on aggregate regions can help to offset the problem, but since policy trends especially are not random, but not readily predictable, this approach remains imperfect. Still, avoiding the excessive pessimism that results from assuming discovery rates will drop to zero will improve forecast accuracy.
Ultimately, the two salient points are that projecting supply is complex, especially since governments have a large say over whether or not investment occurs. The presumption that discoveries and supply cannot be assumed to occur beyond the visible time period, however, leads to a recurring pessimism.
In a 1987 paper, [2] I noted that the major forecasts anticipated a near-term peak in non-OPEC, non-OECD production, despite the fact that the resource base was much less mature than in the OECD areas. A 1995 paper noted that even non-Gulf OPEC members, like Venezuela, were assumed to experience declining production over time, necessitating massive increases in supply from the Gulf countries, especially Saudi Arabia.
Conclusion
How does this pessimism play out in current projections?
Unfortunately, few groups provide national or regional forecasts, although the official forecasts often show regional breakdowns. Without delving into specific country or regional forecasts, Fig. 5 shows projections for non-OPEC production, and interestingly, the EIA sees continued growth while the IEA and OPEC have a peak and decline. In part, the difference in expectations for shale oil (Fig. 6) explains the disparity, but only a small part.
Figure 5: Non-OPEC Supply Forecasts
Figure 6: Shale Oil Forecasts
————
Endnotes
[1] Ehrlich, Paul, Anne H. Ehrlich, and John P. Holdren, W. H. Freeman, 1977, p. 267.
[2] “The Underprojection of Non-OPEC Third World Oil Production,” delivered at the Ninth International Conference of the International Association of Energy Economists, Calgary, Alberta, July 1987, in Proceedings
[…] peak oil is largely a myth, and the climate apocalypse cult is based upon a massive delusion. But humans have better things to […]