One dumb government intervention in energy markets typically begets another, as special interests lobby to counteract the unintended (although not unforeseen) consequences of some previous intervention they championed. The federal ethanol mandate, also known as the renewable fuel standard (RFS), provides a recent example.
Thanks to this Soviet-style production quota system, which Congress created in 2005 and expanded in 2007, daily corn ethanol production in February increased by about 17,000 barrels to 647,000 barrels per day, despite weak motor-fuel demand and poor to negative profit margins for ethanol producers.
Unsurprisingly, inventories of unsold ethanol increased by 1.5 million barrels in February and about 20% of new capacity added last year is idle. An ethanol glut is one of the factors that have bankrupted several ethanol companies. Other factors include high feedstock (corn) prices in 2008–itself a consequence of the mandate—and the collapse of crude oil and gasoline prices in 2009.
To eliminate the glut, the Renewable Fuels Association (RFA) has petitioned EPA to increase from 10% to 15% the amount of ethanol that may be blended into regular gasoline. In other words, RFA proposes to increase by 50% the amount of ethanol you buy each time you fill up. The small-engine industry worries that gasoline containing 15% ethanol might damage lawnmowers, motor boats, generators, and even some cars. Significant research suggests that higher ethanol blends will increase air pollution (see here and here). None of this bothers RFA one bit.
Although not overtly a mandate, raising the blend ceiling to 15% would likely make 15% the industry standard, because refiners are under constant legal pressure to increase the amount of ethanol they blend into the nation’s fuel supply. Under the 2007 RFS, corn ethanol used in motor fuel must increase from 9 billion gallons in 2008 to 15 billion in 2015.
The ethanol industry enjoys a multitude of market-rigging privileges including the RFS, tariffs to keep out cheaper Brazilian ethanol made from sugar cane, and a 45-cents-per-gallon blenders tax credit for each gallon of ethanol sold in motor fuel. Take away those policy stilts, and practically no ethanol would be produced or sold as motor fuel.
But, claim ethanol apologists, ethanol would become fully competitive with gasoline, even out-compete gasoline, if ethanol were “allowed” to compete. Huh? The argument goes like this.
When you buy a new car, you basically have a choice between a car that runs on gasoline and another one that runs on gasoline. Consumers thus have no choice among motor fuels; hence there is no competition in the motor-fuel market. To rectify this market failure, government should mandate that new cars be equipped with flex-fuel technology. Flex-fuel vehicles can run on anything from regular gasoline to E-85 (motor fuel blended with 85% ethanol), and the technology adds only about $100 to the cost of a new vehicle. Mandate flex-fuel technology, and all kinds of wonders will ensue. Consumers will flock to ethanol en masse, billions of dollars we’re sending to petro-states abroad will go to farmers at home, OPEC will crumble, the House of Saud will come a-tumblin’ down.
Beguiled by this argument, Rep. Eliott Engel (D-NY) and Sen. Sam Brownback (R-KS) have introduced bipartisan legislation in their respective chambers (HR 1476, S. 835) to establish an “open fuel standard” (OFS). Each automaker would be required to ensure that at least 50% of the vehicles it manufactures or sells are flex-fuel by 2012 and at least 80% by 2015.
Alas, what flex-fuel mandatists decry as the absence of competition is actually the result of competition. Ethanol as a motor fuel has been around as long as petroleum-based gasoline. In fact, back in the 1920s, Henry Ford reportedly predicted that ethanol would be the “fuel of the future.” The marketplace proved him wrong for what turns out, in hindsight, to be fairly obvious reasons. None of the alternatives to gasoline perform as well in terms of cost, portability, and energy density. And in point of fact, auto companies already make vehicles that run on E-85. About 6 million have been sold in the United States–about six times the number of Prius’s sold worldwide! So, the claim that consumers today can’t choose a flex-fuel vehicle if they want one is bogus.
What the flex-fuel mandatists lament as a lack of competition is simply a competitive outcome they dislike.
If the combination of flex-fuel vehicles and E-85 is such a great bargain, consumers will demand them, and profit-seeking companies will produce and deliver them for sale, all without another mandate. Alternatively, if the flex-fuel/E-85 package is not a good buy, no amount of government meddling can make it so.
Maybe future innovations will make flex-fuel/E-85 a winning combo. Right now, however, filling up with E-85 is a big fat money-loser, as you can see for yourself by visiting www.fueleconomy.gov, a Web site jointly administered by the Department of Energy and the EPA. Once you’re there, click on “Flex-Fuel Vehicles,” then click on “Fuel Economy Information for Flex-Fuel Vehicles,” and then click on “Go.”
EPA and DOE compare the average cost of using regular gasoline and E-85 for scores of different flex-fuel vehicles. In every case, regardless of make or model, fueling the vehicle with E-85 costs more–lots more. Consider a few examples based on fuel prices as of May 1, 2009:
E-85 Regular Gas
Annual Cost Annual Cost
Chevrolet HHR 4WD $1428 $1184
Chrysler Sebring $1697 $1399
Dodge Avenger $1697 $1399
Ford Crown Victoria $1939 $1617
Lincoln Town Car $1939 $1617
GMC Sierra $2088 $1808
Ford Expedition $2468 $1922
Jeep Grand Cherokee $2715 $2051
Mitsubishi Raider $2715 $2051
Toyota Sequoia $2715 $2196
Cadillac Escalade 2WD $2468 $2051
Nissan Armada $2715 $2196
So, for the privilege of spending $100 extra on flex-fuel technology, you can spend hundreds more to fill up your vehicle with E-85 rather than gasoline. Is it any wonder most people don’t buy flex-fuel vehicles?
Mandating the installation of flex-fuel technology would not enhance consumer choice or competition. Indeed, the very idea of a choice-expanding mandate is oxymoronic. Such a mandate would eliminate a choice that most consumers now in fact make–the choice not to buy a flex-fuel vehicle. Mandatists do not want competition. They want a rigged marketplace in which they, rather than competition, dictate the outcomes.
Here are my predictions, if the flex-fuel mandatists get their way:
For this very reason I just bought a 2005 Jeep Liberty with a Diesel engine. The Pathfinder it replaced had trouble using ethanol contaminated gas. I was running it on ethanol free premium gas.
Nice piece Marlo. What is “interesting” are the number of State regulators who seem to be backing away from ethanol, after years of mandatory programas to expand its use. Calif. just adopted a Low Carbon Fuel Standard that (180 degrees from initial place) now actually discouragaes ethanol because of its carbon footprint. And the numer of state vehicle fleets that spent extra taxpayer dollars on the flex fules, but never ever see alternative fuel is legionary. Will folks ever realize (or act) knowing that mandatory purchases, like the RFS and proposed RPS, inevitably INCREASE the cost (or at least the price) for the mandated commodity?
Its a strange strange world we live in were subsidies and mandates spur competition rather than thwart it…
That’s too bad, E85 is sold at a lower price in comparison to gasoline in European countries such as France and Sweden. Is there any hope for change?
[…] is not a lack of competition, but as The Competitive Enterprise Institute’s Marlo Lewis says, it is “simply a competitive outcome they […]
[…] is not a lack of competition, but as The Competitive Enterprise Institute’s Marlo Lewis says, it is “simply a competitive outcome they […]
[…] make a certain percentage of their fleet flex-fuel. What the Competitive Enterprise Institute’s Marlo Lewis writes about that idea applies to a broader alternative vehicle mandate as well: What flex-fuel mandatists […]
[…] market think tanks like the Heritage Foundation (article) and the Competitive Enterprise Institute (article) that do much of the support for climate scepticism and denial, opposition to climate action, and […]
Ethanol has less BTUs but more octane.
Flex fuel vehicles are designed to run on either, but are optimized for gasoline- eg lower compression rations.
What about variable rate positive displacement (turbo and or supercharged) engines that turn up the boast for taking advantage of the Ethanol’s superior octane? I recall a Ford show truck cir 2005 that had the variable rate supercharger yet only for hydrogen and not ethanol.
Why would a manufacture do that?- not adopt that variable supercharge technology for Ethanol fuels?
Also, if the Alberta tar sand petrol fuels are too dirty to burn as straight gasoline or E10 fuel, what about using it for E85, especially with the Ethanol from non corn commodities as algae and hemp?
Marlo
Combine “any fuel” with “flex fuel” and now you have competition with methanol/gasoline or diesel from coal. That would provide serious competition, reduce driving costs and reduce imports.
China has already installed enough coal to methanol capacity to provide more than 50% of fuel consumption for cheaper than importing fuel. With more coal resources why couldn’t the USA do better?
See: China’s growing methanol economy and its implications for energy
and the environment, Chi-Jen Yang & Robert B. Jackson Energy Policy 41 (2012) 878–884
And the Methanol Institute
Promote serious competition. Mandating “any fuel” with “flex fuel” vehicles would be the cheapest simplest way to break the gasoline/diesel monopoly and open the way to serious fuel competition and import reduction.